|
Close
window to return
|
5 March 2001
How much does the public care about health
inequalities?
Peter Smith, Paul Dolan, Rebecca Shaw, Aki Tsuchiya and Alan Williams
Background
- The government's
public health agenda has the objective of "improving the health
of everyone, especially the worst off" - that is, of improving
health and reducing health inequalities. The focus on health inequalities
was reiterated in the National Plan, and made concrete by the announcement
by the Secretary of State of specific health inequality targets on 28
February 2001.
- Health inequalities
have been a major and persistent policy problem in the UK, and many
commentators (including ourselves) welcome the current government's
clear commitment to their reduction. However, the targeting by the NHS
of health inequalities diverts funds from more traditional NHS activity.
That is, with a fixed NHS budget, efforts to reduce health inequalities
may imply some reduction in the total health improvement achieved by
the NHS.
- Ministers must
decide what proportion of NHS funds to target at the reduction of health
inequalities. To make this decision on an informed basis they require
evidence from a range of sources. These can be considered under two
broad headings:
Our study
- Our study, Measuring
preferences regarding equity and variations in health, is a collaboration
between the Universities of York and Sheffield, and is funded by the
ESRC Health Variations Programme. It seeks to offer for the first time
rigorous evidence on the strength of public feeling relating to health
inequalities. It has asked ordinary members of the public how much traditional
NHS care they are prepared to sacrifice in order to reduce inequalities.
The study comprised three main stages:
Key findings
Focus Groups and
in-depth interviews
- Respondents were
presented with information on existing health inequalities, and were
asked to comment on their causes and consequences. Overall, the health
inequalities information presented was well understood and was familiar
to most of the respondents: "you know that people with money
live longer and better, don't you". However, all were surprised
by the magnitude of the differences between social classes: "I'm
surprised that there is such a difference. The difference is startling.
It's a terrible thing".
Interviews
- We developed a
structured questionnaire, which asked respondents to indicate the extent
to which they were prepared to sacrifice some element of health gain
for the total population in order to secure a health improvement for
a particularly disadvantaged group. The questionnaire was administered
through 130 one-to-one interviews with residents from the York area.
- Health inequalities
were defined in terms of average life expectancy and rates of limiting
long-term illness. Respondents were presented with health differences
between:
- the highest and
lowest social classes,
- between men and
women,
- between smokers
and non-smokers,
- between groups
defined simply as the 'healthiest 20%' and the 'unhealthiest 20%' of
the population.
- We found that many
people are keen to reduce health inequalities. Indeed, there is a widespread
willingness to redirect considerable resources towards people with adverse
health prospects, at the expense of other NHS activity, in line with
the government's public health policy.
- There are, however,
two details of interest. First, there seems to be considerable variation
between individuals in the importance attached to reducing health inequalities
(for example, about 40% of respondents favour no targeting of a health
inequality based on social class).
- Second, the strength
of opinion about reducing inequalities varies considerably depending
on the way in which the inequalities are described. For example, people
are much keener to reduce life expectancy inequalities defined by social
class than they are to reduce identical inequalities defined by smoking
status or gender.
- The appendix presents
some detailed results. For life expectancy, the central (median) response
indicated that an intervention offering 6 months improvement in life
expectancy to the lowest social class is regarded as equivalent to an
intervention offering 2 years improvement to the highest social class.
This is very similar to the response obtained when the sub-groups are
defined in terms of the "healthiest" and "unhealthiest"
20% of the population. It indicates considerable willingness to target
deprived populations.
- In contrast, when
identical life expectancy data are presented but sub-groups are defined
by gender, about 60% of respondents favour no targeting of the inequality.
We have not yet been able to determine the reason for the increased
resistance to tackling the inequality, but it may be due to a belief
that - in contrast to the social class inequality - it is effectively
unavoidable.
- When the questions
were framed in terms of long-term illness, the central response suggested
that an 8.5% reduction in the rate of long-term illness for the lowest
social class was equivalent to a 2% reduction for the highest social
class. A similar response was obtained when the sub-groups used are
the healthiest and unhealthiest 20%. When identical data are presented
but sub-groups are defined by smoking status, more than 50% of respondents
favour no targeting of the inequality. Again, we can only speculate
on the reason for the increased resistance to tackling this inequality,
but it may be due to a belief that it is to some extent self-inflicted.
Postal Questionnaire
- In the light of
these successes, we moved on to develop a postal survey instrument,
based on a simplified version of the questionnaire. The dataset of about
850 responses is now ready for analysis. It is expected that preliminary
results will be available around Easter 2001.
Policy implications
- Many people are
willing to target considerable NHS resources at the reduction of health
inequalities. There is therefore already widespread support for current
policy.
- Although the existence
of health inequalities is widely understood, the magnitude of the inequalities
often surprises respondents. Increased provision of information to
the public on the nature and magnitude of health inequalities is likely
to increase support for health inequality policy still further.
- The variation
in public views is nevertheless considerable.
For any given health inequality, at least 40% of the population is not
persuaded that traditional NHS activity should be sacrificed in order
to address the inequality.
- Willingness to
tackle a health inequality varies depending on how it is described.
For example, a majority of respondents are unwilling to target NHS resources
at an inequality defined by smoking status or gender. This suggests
that the general public's response to health inequality policy may be
highly dependent on how the policy is presented.
The study team:
Paul Dolan, Sheffield
Health Economics Group, University of Sheffield
Rebecca Shaw Centre for Health Economics, University of York
Peter C. Smith, Centre for Health Economics, University of York
Aki Tsuchiya, Sheffield Health Economics Group, University of Sheffield.
Alan Williams, Centre for Health Economics, University of York
Further details:
Peter C. Smith
Centre for Health Economics
University of York
York
YO10 5DD
Telephone: 01904-433779
E-mail: pcs1@york.ac.uk
Further reading:
Dolan, P., Shaw, R., Smith, P., Tsuchiya, A. and Williams, A. (2000),
To maximise health or to reduce inequalities in health? Towards a social
welfare function based on stated preference data, York : Centre for
Health Economics, University of York.
Shaw R., Dolan, P., Tsuchiya, A., Williams, A., Smith, P. and Burrows,
R. (2001), Development of a questionnaire to elicit people's preferences
regarding health inequalities: Occasional Paper, York : Centre for
Health Economics, University of York.
Appendix: detailed
findings
In the questions concerning life expectancy, respondents are asked initially
to choose between programme A, which increases the life expectancy of
both social groups by 2 years, and Programme B, which increases only the
life expectancy of social class V, but does so by 4 years. Those respondents
who choose Programme B are then offered a succession of less attractive
alternatives, in which the benefit to social class V is steadily reduced.
The intention is to identify at which point (if any) the improvement in
health for the disadvantaged group offered by Programme B becomes unacceptable
when viewed alongside the reduction in health suffered by the healthier
group.
Table 1 presents the results for tackling inequalities in average life
expectancy. The first row gives the number of respondents who were not
prepared to sacrifice any total health gain in order to reduce the stated
inequality. For those who were prepared to make such a trade-off, the
following rows then give the point at which felt the benefits to the less
healthy group were not adequate compensation for the denial of benefits
to the healthier group.
Table 1: Average life expectancy questions
The median respondent
felt that a gain of 6 months to the lowest social class should be regarded
as equivalent to a gain of 2 years to the highest social class. This is
also the median response when the sub-groups are defined in terms of the
healthiest and unhealthiest quintiles of the population. In contrast,
when identical data are presented but sub-groups are defined by sex, the
median preference is to favour no targeting of men at all.
Table 2 shows similar results when the questions were framed in terms
of long-term illness. The median respondent felt that an 8.5% reduction
in the rate of long-term illness for the lowest social class was equivalent
to a 2% reduction for the highest social class. When the sub-groups used
are the healthiest and unhealthiest quintile, the median respondent felt
that a 10% reduction for the unhealthy to be equivalent to a 2% reduction
for the healthy. When identical data are presented but sub-groups are
defined by smoking status, the median preference is to favour no targeting
of smokers at all.
Table 2: Limiting
long-term illness questions
|